Buy new:
$34.25
FREE delivery May 15 - 31
Ships from: GrandEagleRetail
Sold by: GrandEagleRetail
$34.25
FREE delivery May 15 - 31. Details
Only 6 left in stock - order soon.
$$34.25 () Includes selected options. Includes initial monthly payment and selected options. Details
Price
Subtotal
$$34.25
Subtotal
Initial payment breakdown
Shipping cost, delivery date, and order total (including tax) shown at checkout.
Ships from
GrandEagleRetail
Ships from
GrandEagleRetail
Returns
Eligible for Return, Refund or Replacement within 30 days of receipt
Eligible for Return, Refund or Replacement within 30 days of receipt
This item can be returned in its original condition for a full refund or replacement within 30 days of receipt. You may receive a partial or no refund on used, damaged or materially different returns.
Returns
Eligible for Return, Refund or Replacement within 30 days of receipt
This item can be returned in its original condition for a full refund or replacement within 30 days of receipt. You may receive a partial or no refund on used, damaged or materially different returns.
Payment
Secure transaction
Your transaction is secure
We work hard to protect your security and privacy. Our payment security system encrypts your information during transmission. We don’t share your credit card details with third-party sellers, and we don’t sell your information to others. Learn more
Payment
Secure transaction
We work hard to protect your security and privacy. Our payment security system encrypts your information during transmission. We don’t share your credit card details with third-party sellers, and we don’t sell your information to others. Learn more
$29.99
Get Fast, Free Shipping with Amazon Prime FREE Returns
FREE delivery Tuesday, May 7 on orders shipped by Amazon over $35
Or fastest delivery Thursday, May 2. Order within 13 hrs
Only 1 left in stock - order soon.
$$34.25 () Includes selected options. Includes initial monthly payment and selected options. Details
Price
Subtotal
$$34.25
Subtotal
Initial payment breakdown
Shipping cost, delivery date, and order total (including tax) shown at checkout.
Access codes and supplements are not guaranteed with used items.
Loading your book clubs
There was a problem loading your book clubs. Please try again.
Not in a club? Learn more
Amazon book clubs early access

Join or create book clubs

Choose books together

Track your books
Bring your club to Amazon Book Clubs, start a new book club and invite your friends to join, or find a club that’s right for you for free.
Kindle app logo image

Download the free Kindle app and start reading Kindle books instantly on your smartphone, tablet, or computer - no Kindle device required.

Read instantly on your browser with Kindle for Web.

Using your mobile phone camera - scan the code below and download the Kindle app.

QR code to download the Kindle App

Follow the authors

Something went wrong. Please try your request again later.

Degrowth (The Economy: Key Ideas) Paperback – June 30, 2018

4.2 4.2 out of 5 stars 32 ratings

{"desktop_buybox_group_1":[{"displayPrice":"$34.25","priceAmount":34.25,"currencySymbol":"$","integerValue":"34","decimalSeparator":".","fractionalValue":"25","symbolPosition":"left","hasSpace":false,"showFractionalPartIfEmpty":true,"offerListingId":"zN%2Bss6x54iBRIjK%2BBEHbEZfvpkPzvTPaLrLz7Qt5779mynexl119UjULgucirQsfKzup5n7azIJs7uIgHCRJdla6uqAJgDDvXCi74RYQ4bJ4%2FQZodW81W5oy6yxKlz6GqIyBUPCeu6CBw0dZjjxjKnQeCHOWpMEcEyZrgyMsaLcUbhQIJ7NRpqqi3F3w6YVQ","locale":"en-US","buyingOptionType":"NEW","aapiBuyingOptionIndex":0}, {"displayPrice":"$29.99","priceAmount":29.99,"currencySymbol":"$","integerValue":"29","decimalSeparator":".","fractionalValue":"99","symbolPosition":"left","hasSpace":false,"showFractionalPartIfEmpty":true,"offerListingId":"zN%2Bss6x54iBRIjK%2BBEHbEZfvpkPzvTPafQJcKYaxj9z%2Fxm7OoiCfhRaV27o6KzmcrhpvhWbXaXv9QKrBEXu25GfAT82gHWo2gAFNOyoNTrY9pQ2snKTmlcQfQd%2FrrwlTNqGYDYfHRrBaFvCWRB8qXgeIId1enBE9uhjpWTJ%2Bg%2BDuSR%2FAbvOc3S4L4PGeCI0K","locale":"en-US","buyingOptionType":"USED","aapiBuyingOptionIndex":1}]}

Purchase options and add-ons

The term “degrowth” has emerged within ecological and other heterodox schools of economics as a critique of the idea (and ideology) of economic growth. Degrowth argues that economic growth is no longer desirable – its costs exceed its benefits – and advocates a transformation of economies so that they produce and consume less, differently and better.

Giorgos Kallis provides a clear and succinct guide to the central ideas of degrowth theory and explores what it would take for an economy to transition to a position that enables it to prosper without growth. The book examines how mainstream conceptualizations of the economy are challenged by degrowth theory and how degrowth draws on a multifaceted network of ideas across disciplines to shed new light on the economic process. The central claims of the degrowth literature are discussed alongside some key criticisms of them. Whether one agrees or disagrees with degrowth’s critique of economic growth, Kallis shows how it raises fundamental questions about the workings of capitalism that we can no longer afford to ignore.

The Amazon Book Review
The Amazon Book Review
Book recommendations, author interviews, editors' picks, and more. Read it now.

Frequently bought together

$34.25
Get it May 15 - 31
Only 6 left in stock - order soon.
Ships from and sold by GrandEagleRetail.
+
$17.78
Get it as soon as Monday, May 6
In Stock
Ships from and sold by Amazon.com.
+
$19.10
Get it as soon as Monday, May 6
In Stock
Ships from and sold by Amazon.com.
Total price:
To see our price, add these items to your cart.
Details
Added to Cart
Some of these items ship sooner than the others.
Choose items to buy together.

Editorial Reviews

Review

This is a sparkling book. It is both an urgent rallying cry and a measured and accessible introduction to the topic. Brimming with insight and humour, it tackles the question that will shape aeons: if human society doesn't learn to shrink its material footprint the consequences will be dire – so how can that task be approached? Anyone who wishes that earth remains habitable should read this book. -- Gareth Dale, Brunel University London

“Kallis’s personality resonates through the pages ... clear, approachable and often humorous ... he succeeds in making Degrowth accessible to a wide audience ... the pace is well suited to those new to the subject, including students. Kallis skillfully unpacks complex concepts and provides a consistent stream of accessible analogies.” -- Maxwell Hartt, Economic Geography

Mandatory reading for students, researchers and practitioners interested not only in degrowth, but also more generally in economics, politics and sustainability. The book's arguments are highly significant to tackle the key challenges of the twenty-first century – climate change, rising global inequality, economic crises ... well written: scholarly yet accessible, rigorously argued but with humor and full of everyday examples ... A welcome addition to degrowth scholarship and will have considerable influence on teaching degrowth at both undergraduate and graduate levels. -- Matthias Schmelzer, Ecological Economics

A thought-provoking, informative and comprehensive resource ... offers both a justification as well as a vision and new imaginary for degrowth ... Kallis’ hypotheses and theories are well- researched, and linked to empirical data. -- Sarah Hafner, Centre for the Understanding of Sustainable Prosperity (CUSP) blog

About the Author

Giorgos Kallis is Professor of Ecological Economics and Political Ecology at ICTA, Autonomous University of Barcelona. He has been a Leverhulme visiting professor at SOAS, University of London and a Marie Curie International Fellow at the University of California, Berkeley.

Product details

  • Publisher ‏ : ‎ Agenda Publishing (June 30, 2018)
  • Language ‏ : ‎ English
  • Paperback ‏ : ‎ 240 pages
  • ISBN-10 ‏ : ‎ 1911116800
  • ISBN-13 ‏ : ‎ 978-1911116806
  • Item Weight ‏ : ‎ 11.2 ounces
  • Dimensions ‏ : ‎ 5.75 x 0.75 x 8.25 inches
  • Customer Reviews:
    4.2 4.2 out of 5 stars 32 ratings

About the authors

Follow authors to get new release updates, plus improved recommendations.

Customer reviews

4.2 out of 5 stars
4.2 out of 5
32 global ratings

Top reviews from the United States

Reviewed in the United States on August 10, 2021
One of the most influential books and ideas I ever encountered was Herman Daly's "Steady-State Economics." I read the 1977 original after reading about it in "Not Man Apart," the Friends of the Earth publication. The idea that the size of human society and its economy should not be growing (in terms of material throughput) is therefore not new to me. The idea of "degrowth" as necessary to eventually arrive at that steady-state economy is a more recent idea that is gaining attention in the context of our ever more serious ecological crisis.

This 2018 book by Georgos Kallis certainly seems to be a good overview and introduction. It is an academic book, with 21 pages of references and full of arguments with competing ideas. Kallis is embedded in ecological economics, the sub-field that Daly was key in creating. Degrowth is interdisciplinary, though, and the key thinker is Serge Latouche, an economist and anthropologist, who brought ecological economics together with political ecology, philosophy, and post-development theory. He defines degrowth as "a process of building an autonomous, convivial society" (10).

This book should become part of the higher education curriculum, and environmental activists need to know about the idea of degrowth. It is a critical rejoinder to any notion of "sustainable growth" or "sustainable capitalism."

(verified purchase from the Cosmic Book Emporium)
One person found this helpful
Report
Reviewed in the United States on January 29, 2019
"Degrowth" connotes a broad range of critiques of the dogma that societies need economic growth, and that more growth is better. This is a good book for introducing degrowth to an academically-inclined audience and perhaps to activists on the left as well.

Among the book's virtues is that the author (GK) writes in a clear, mostly jargon-free style, even when some of the ideas he discusses are abstract. This is harder to achieve than it sounds. Another strength is that he devotes a lot of space to political aspects of degrowth, in contrast to most other writers who see the topic as primarily, or even almost exclusively, economic. The political theme is especially prominent in Chapter 5, "The Utopia of Degrowth," which discusses specific policies and political pragmatics to a greater extent than I can recall seeing anywhere else in the English-language degrowth literature. The book also emphasizes the distinction between exchange value and use value in economics, with an emphasis on the relevance of the latter concept -- effectively absent from mainstream economic theory -- to degrowth.

One factor that might limit the book's readership is its orientation towards theory. In this it retains the spirit of the important 2015 volume GK co-edited, 
Degrowth: A Vocabulary for a New Era . Topics like the labor theory of value (see below) are discussed at length, even though this it isn't necessarily dispositive for policy. GK also follows the earlier volume in advocating "dépense," the practice of spending money on useless things for the community, such as feasts. As I noted in my review of the earlier book, from a practical political point of view I can't imagine many voters warming up to the idea of deliberately wasting public money -- it seems more an idea for scholars to enjoy. Nonetheless GK does give a clearer and more concrete explanation of the topic than in the "Vocabulary," so if you're intrigued by the idea, this book offers a good exposition.

A more significant limitation might be that the book seems to assume its readership comes from a political and intellectual space on the left. If you like the writings of David Harvey, and if you tend to favor publishers like Verso, Pluto and Polity for your non-fiction reading, you could very likely find this book quite appealing. On the other hand, if you're scandalized by an author who takes Marxian ideas seriously, this book isn't for you.

For example, the discussion of exchange value and use value is expressed in terms of lengthy discussions of the "labor theory of value," a concept introduced by Adam Smith but that plays a much more prominent role in Marxist thought. There are less provocative ways of presenting the topic of use value, such as via a discussion of Aristotle's distinction between types of exchange: exchanges whose goal is to accumulate money, and exchanges whose goal is to acquire things the purchaser will use. (For Aristotle and the roots of use value generally, see Scott Meikle, Aristotle's Economic Thought (Oxford UP 1995); for more in English on Aristotle and degrowth, see my working paper "Unlimited Growth: Paradise or Paradox?" (2010), posted on the Social Science Research Network.) The Marxian framing of the issue may be fine for some readers but a turn-off for others. I'm an advocate of degrowth, and agree with GK on many points. But if I think of the main groups I'm most interested in persuading about the benefits of degrowth -- undergraduate business students, local businesspeople, and voters in a conservative country like Japan, where I live -- I'm quite sure that Aristotle would be a safer bet.

This is a pity, because there's a need for an up-to-date book like this -- especially with its attention to politics -- that could introduce degrowth to agnostics and skeptics across the political spectrum.

The rest of this long review focuses in some detail on two areas that I hope will be revisited in the next edition of the book: finance, and the discussion of the connections between certain physics concepts and economics.

A. FINANCE: Currently, the book speaks of finance mainly in the context of debt bearing compound interest. That kind of interest grows exponentially with the passage of time, and much more quickly than simple interest. The argument is that in order to pay off this endlessly-growing interest, you need to produce and sell an ever-growing amount of goods and services: economic growth.

The weakness of the argument is that modern finance isn't so anchored to the real, material economy of goods and services -- the economy measured by GDP. Since sometime before start of the 21st Century, financial markets became **many times bigger** than global GDP. How is that possible? Because although brokerage fees and income from financial services are included in GDP, the value of sales of financial instruments on financial markets is not. Just considering equity (stock) markets alone, the annual global sales volume is bigger than global GDP. Then add in bond markets, commodities markets, derivatives markets (the one that caused the 2008 crash) and foreign exchange markets (the biggest), and you have a much bigger playground than the real economy of goods and services. Moreover, profits on these markets (known as "capital gains") are much less evenly shared than the salaries and other paychecks that get rolled into GDP: in the US, roughly 49% of all capital gains go to the richest 0.1% of the population. In other words, if you're a rich person, what happens on these markets is much more important than what happens in the real economy.

This book doesn't mention anything about the disconnect between these markets and GDP. Instead, it only asserts that financial gains from "speculation" are "simply a redistribution of value produced elsewhere in the economy;" while this "may give the impression of growth decoupled from resource constraints," that impression is "an illusion" (@178). No further explanation is given. The use of the word "growth" in this statement is something of a distraction, since in our current political economy that term refers to growth in GDP -- and GDP, as explained above, isn't directly pertinent to modern financial markets. More importantly, this summary dismissal of financial gains as "illusion" isn't sufficient to explain the reality of modern finance. The financial gains from speculation are bigger than global GDP altogether -- so they can't simply be a redistribution of value from the real economy.

But, you might object: doesn't all that money come back into the real economy through purchases of yachts, vacations on private islands, thousand-dollar-per-week cigar expense, etc.? No. Rich people don't spend everything they own. A lot of the money is tied up in illiquid assets. Moreover, price increases don't have to be funded by increased production. Suppose you paid cash to buy a house in Palo Alto, CA, in 2015 at the then-median price -- ca. $2.5 million --, and you want to sell it in January 2019, preferably to a buyer who pays cash, again at the median price -- roughly $3.2 million. (Yes, there are people who pay cash for such houses.) Does your buyer's extra $700K have to come from economic growth? Not at all - it could come from, among other possibilities, selling equities in the bull market that lasted most of the way through 2018, or in the early 2019 rally. (If you believe in the fairy-tale that stock prices are related to fundamentals in the real economy, then suppose the profits came from shorting stock in the late 2018 downturn, or from forex trading, or from derivatives, etc.) That is, the source of increased speculative value in one market (housing) can be increased speculative value in another (the stock market). And both the buyer's profits on the stock market and your $700K profit on the house sale are capital gains, not included in GDP.

Beyond this, the rich have another use for money -- power. As John Kenneth Galbraith was fond of pointing out, power is something economics tries to pretend doesn't exist. (E.g., The Economics of Innocent Fraud (2004).) Why else do billionaires fret about their ranking on the Forbes list? Does someone with, say, $20 billion in wealth really spend much more than someone with only $10 billion? But merely by having $20 billion in wealth, they are probably able to command much more attention than someone with only half as much.

So the materialist account of finance in books like the present seems not to address adequately the realities of finance and the power of money. Its mechanistic explanation of the need for growth is too simple. There are many other reasons that can explain why our current approach to economics favors infinite growth. For one, political pressures dating back to the Cold War period, when growth became the imperative for national policy and a declining growth rate risked getting you kicked out of office. For another, the simple psychological insight of Aristotle, that when you focus your desire on wealth measured by something as arbitrary as a number, there isn't any inherent limit. To be fair to GK, though, I have yet to see any English-language book about degrowth that adequately explains the role of the financial economy. I hope that a 2nd edition will reconsider finance from a broader perspective.

B. ENTROPY, ETC. A number of the arguments and claims in Chapter 2, apropos of the roles of energy and entropy in the economy, need repair. For example, GK defines the physical concept of work as "intentional energy expenditure that alters the object to which it is directed" (@28). Unfortunately, that's not quite right. The convective cells in in your morning coffee, a river that pushes pebbles and silt along its flow, a hurricane that blows a roof off a house or a reporter off his feet: in each of these systems, a force is doing work without involving any intention. The text also falls into the very common error of comparing entropy to physical order, here compounded by the claim (@26) that energy must be input in order to turn liquids, such as water (disorder) into solids, such as ice (order). Actually, most crystallization processes -- the freezing of water, the solidification of metals, etc. -- are exothermic: far from needing energy inputs, they release energy. (Of course the temperature at which you attempt these operations does matter: e.g., on a winter day in my northern Japan hometown I can just put some water outdoors to make ice, but if I were in Barcelona I'd usually need a refrigerator to do so. This is in line with the laws of thermodynamics, too: without a fridge, the heat in the Barcelona air will deliver energy to the ice cube, breaking the intermolecular bonds and melting it: opposite to what this book says. )

Some of GK's arguments are based on those of one of the patron saints of degrowth, the economist Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen (1906-1994), known to many as NGR. Inspired by the Second Law of Thermodynamics, NGR claimed that all economic processes inevitably lead to waste, in the form of heat and material. Whether NGR's arguments are true as a matter of fundamental physical laws or simply as a practical matter has been a subject of controversy -- but at least as a practical matter, they're pretty much accurate. So it's a little odd that, just like conventional economics textbooks, GK's diagram illustrating "a general scheme of the economic process" (Fig. 2.4 @59) doesn't show waste of any type at all. This should be rethought for the next edition.

NGR was also a prophet of scarcity, claiming that there is a finite stock of "low entropy energy" (including oil, coal, and other fossil fuels) with which the Earth was endowed; there is also an extractive flow when we burn this fuel, leading us to lose it as "high entropy" heat. Like most other writers on degrowth and many other ecological economists besides, GK echoes this idea of a finite stock (@27). But this narrative is incomplete: NGR and most of his followers neglect that there's also a creative or incoming flow. Quite contrary to NGR's mystical thesis about entropy, the creation of fossil fuels is thermodynamically favored -- they're being created even during the few minutes that you're reading this review. If we stopped using them now, then eventually the supply would come back to 18th Century levels. We'd just need to wait tens or hundreds of millions of years, which is well within the timeframe for the continued stability of the Sun (ca. 5 billion years). So the supply problem faced by fossil fuel-reliant economies isn't a finite stock: it's that the rate at which new fossil fuels are being created is much slower than the rate at which we're consuming them (on the order of hundreds of years).

Unfortunately, NGR's emphasis on thermodynamics has captivated his followers. Unfortunate, because reaction rates aren't explained simply by thermodynamics: you also need to consider chemical kinetics. Kinetics relies on a physics paradigm known as statistical mechanics, which by the early 20th Century could explain pretty much everything 19th Century thermodynamics could, and then some. But due to some misunderstandings about entropy and the "arrow of time," NGR thought statistical mechanics was bunk, which led his theories astray. So he ignored kinetics, as have most of his defenders and even critics. (Among critics, an early exception was A.O. Converse (1996); see also a 2010 paper by M.D. Glucina and K. Mayumi. For more about kinetics and degrowth discourse see section A.5 of my working paper "The Birth of Décroissance" (2017), on SSRN.)

Fortunately, the truth or accuracy of NGR's arguments isn't a pre-condition for degrowth's being a good idea. As a practical matter, the book's discussion of why fossil fuels are scarce over relevant time scales would be relatively simple to fix, and I hope GK will consider doing so. Some readers of this review might wonder, though, why all this matters. If your background is in economics or other social science, maybe you'll feel that the difference between thermodynamics and kinetics is academic hair-splitting. The response to that argument is two-fold: #1, from a physics point of view, it's not a trivial distinction. And #2, degrowth isn't such a popular position that its advocates can afford to be loose about their arguments. Weak science is an easy target for critics who want to dismiss the idea of degrowth out of hand.

In sum, this is a generally good book, with some room for improvement in a couple of specific areas. I'm disappointed that it wouldn't be suitable for use in my own teaching, since most of my students have been imbibing a very conventional economics education, or are even interested in pursuing an MBA. A sizable chunk of that audience, as well as voters without any formal economics training, eventually must be persuaded if degrowth is to become a practical reality. But in the meantime, there's an audience for this book, too, and I expect they will hold it in high regard.

[PS after posting: I read the paperback edition, and didn't realize Amazon would attribute this review to the Kindle edition. Page references refer to the paperback; I don't know if the Kindle edition allows true page numbering.]
15 people found this helpful
Report

Top reviews from other countries

Translate all reviews to English
Maricela Regalado
5.0 out of 5 stars Muy buen libro
Reviewed in Mexico on December 8, 2023
El libro aborda temas muy interesantes, lo recomiendo mucho.
Cliente Amazon
5.0 out of 5 stars Everyone should read it
Reviewed in Germany on December 1, 2018
Kallis' ideas are inspiring. Very easy way to understand degrowth and its importance to the future.
Miss Vanessa Spedding
5.0 out of 5 stars Five Stars
Reviewed in the United Kingdom on August 12, 2018
Essential reading for our times; well researched and written.
One person found this helpful
Report
Jonas Lipski
2.0 out of 5 stars Uninformed ideology.
Reviewed in Germany on November 6, 2023
Kallis discusses a great range of topics, from philosophy to physics to economics to politics and back. He is not competent in any of these areas. His discussion of marginalism is one of the most ironic things I ever read in a non-fiction book: He aims to demonstrate that marginalism is "unscientific" because it has never been "proven" and discusses it with the competence of a first-year student that barely grasped one or two basic ideas connected to it. After he "refuted" marginalism he goes on discussing Marx's theory of value and states that Marx has developed it as a critique of "market economics" (read marginalism). At this point I was literally laughing, since nothing in Marx's publications shows any clue that he was even aware of marginalism; and his Capital 1 was published years before marginalism was developed.

If you are interested in the ideology of confused modern youngsters that shout "system change!" on the streets, read this book - its a good example for this confused ideology. If you are interested in gaining knowledge about subjects such as economics, political theory, social philosophy, or anything alike - this book is not for you, as Kallis has no knowledge in any of these areas and just spreads his incompetence.
Anthony K Kinder
4.0 out of 5 stars Green-growth no alternative to urgent environmental crisis
Reviewed in the United Kingdom on April 2, 2020
He rejects green growth in favour of degrowth ie absolute and urgent decoupling from carbon-enabled economy and social relations. Oddly, he rejects a labour theory of value; odd, since he goes on to favour a radical left-wing change programme including wholesale public ownership. He privileges ecology over economy without plausibly addressing issues of poverty and inequality, especially those in emerging and developing countries. Odd too, he favours national state rather than internationally-cooperative degrowth solutions. Overall, worth a read, well-referenced and argued, if in the end an unconvincing case for degrowth, inadequate treatment of important theory, and surprisingly insufficient attention to the green-growth perspective and planned change, which after all is perhaps the majority one in eco-economics circles.
One person found this helpful
Report